Coins with nominal value Part I. Part III.
Part IV.
It is believed that the first of the best-known attempts to introduce
credit money was made by Emperor Nero, who decreased the content
of gold in coins (common folk at the time believed he was «spoiling»
coins). Thus, for the first time in history the value of metal in a coin
became lower than its nominal value, but still was high enough to define
consumer properties of metal. Gold, circulating as jewelry, at present is always mixed with copper,
silver, nickel and zinc to increase its shine and durability. Consumer
properties of such gold improve, but its exchange value as the goldcontaining
metal decreases. Thus, if gold was «diluted» by other metals
to an insignificant measure, there was no social controversy. However,
as soon as this proportion exceeded the limits of what was accepted by
the public conscience, unrest grew and riots sprung up — thus the society
tried to make the State executives change their viewpoint. «At first coin minting was a private trade (in Russia, for example,
coin minters were known as “livtsy” — “casters” and “serebryaniki” —
“silversmiths”). Then minting was monopolized by the State and coin
production began at State premises known as Mints. In the world of ancient civilizations, as has already been stated above,
coins were made from pure silver and gold (Greece) or their alloy (Lydia).
Then they started adding hardeners (for instance, copper in gold alloys).
Too high an amount of hardener resulted in coin spoiling. Coin spoiling by the State is a deliberate act of decreasing the weight
or the standard of coins while preserving their face value, in order to
get profit142 This means that, together with the monopoly on coin minting,
the State got the opportunity to spoil coins. The decrease of the amount of metal in coins is usually more or less
palpable and is achieved by various means. For example, it is done by
simply decreasing the weight of freshly minted coins without any damage
to the quality of metal or by spoiling the metal, mixing it with a
cheap additive, whilst the weight of coins either stays the same or increases.
Also, sometimes a precious metal is simply replaced by a nonprecious
one. Coin spoiling was broadly practiced in slave-trading and feudal
societies, especially during wars which put all involved parties in a tense
financial situation. Thus, in Rome the weight of coins was a kind of
barometer, which indicated periods, when tyrannical power of the
Emperor, or social unrest, significantly increased. Historians provide
us with the following evidence: a silver denarius during the reign of
Augustus (63 BC — AD 14) weighed 3.89g; in Nero’s time (37–68), its
weight went down to 3.41g and 15 percent of additive was mixed in. In
Commodus’ time (161–192), it weighed 2.85g and the amount of additive
had grown up to 50 percent; at Septimius Severus’ time (146–
211), it’s already up to 60 percent, and an old denarius is now twice as
expensive as a new one. Quite often coins had a copper core, covered
with thin silver plating. This was nothing else but official counterfeiting
of coins»143 It was coin spoiling that demonstrated the State’s power. Common
folk and traders accepted these coins because, on the one hand, it was
acceptable for paying taxes, and, on the other, apparently, the State
could force traders to accept this and no other money as the means of
payment for their goods. Coins began to differentiate into full-value coins and change. Fullvalue
coins are a type of monetary unit in the form of an ingot (usually
round-shaped), made from an alloy containing a precious metal. Face
value of a full-value coin was equal to the value of the amount of precious
metal contained in it. Billon coins are another sort of monetary
units, looking the same as full-value coins, but, in contrast to the latter,
their face value was higher than the value of the alloy they were made
from, as well as higher than their production cost. Copper coins (fig.17) nominated in silver, minted in the time of
Russian Tsar Nicholas I (1840), can serve as an example144 Èëëþñòðàöèè èç êíèãè À. Þ. Ãðèáîâà "Äåíüãè è öåííûå áóìàãè: ñóùíîñòü è ïðàâîâîé ðåæèì" Èëëþñòðàöèè èç êíèãè À. Þ. Ãðèáîâà "Äåíüãè è öåííûå áóìàãè: ñóùíîñòü è ïðàâîâîé ðåæèì" In Russia, coin spoiling by Princes and Tsars, spoiling of silver
«grivnas» by cutting off pieces and the emergence of «thief» money led
to complete disappearance of full-weight coins, social unrest and riots
(«copper riot» in the time of Tsar Alexei Mikhailovich in the mid.-17th
century) Trying to avoid difficulties, the government began to mint
copper money with an enforced exchange rate. As a result, the market
value of the silver rouble began to grow compared to its face value,
silver almost entirely disappeared from circulation and was hoarded by
money-lenders and money-changers, and commodity prices in general
went up. Difficulties experienced by «bimetallic» countries are explained by
Copernicus-Gresham’s Law, discovered in 1526 by the Polish scholar
Nicolaus Copernicus and in 1560 by the English financier Sir Thomas
Gresham: «Bad money drives good money out of circulation"145. This
means, that if two kinds of coins, interconnected by a legal correlation
of exchange, are in circulation in the same country at the same time,
there arises the trend for disappearance of the better (in terms of their commercial value) coins. What happens is precisely this: good money
is either hoarded or used in foreign trade, or remelted and then exchanged
for bad money. Eventually, copper money was withdrawn from circulation. In the
late 17th century, the amount of silver in rouble coins was decreased by
30%. In Russia, up until the 17th century, mining of precious metals was
extremely underdeveloped, and because of that Mints, which in the 17th
century were monopolized by the State, remelted foreign coins. According
to the «monetary regalia» of Peter the Great, export of precious
metal bars was strictly banned, whilst export of spoilt coins was allowed. As the price of the precious metal component in coins with low face
value continues to grow, there arises a problem of the object component
of coin value being higher than its liability component. «The Swiss Government decided, from the 1st of January 2007, to
withdraw from circulation one-centime coins (0.0076 US dollars). It
costs 11 centimes to produce a one-centime coin, as Hans-Rudolf
Merz, Head of the Federal Department of Finance, has calculated. His
plan included saving another 230 500 dollars by eliminating five-centime
coins as well, but consumer organizations, fearing that round
numbers on price tags would in fact mean growth of prices, won the
fight to save five-centime coins. ÑThe cost of metal content in United States one-cent coins (97.5%
zinc core, 2.5% copper plating) rose up to 77% of their face value. Also,
if one adds the minting and distribution costs (0.0061 dollars per one
cent), it turns out that the United States Mint’s costs involved in producing
a one-cent coin exceed its face value by 38%. The US cent has
been through this before: in 1982 the cost of its copper content exceeded
its face value, and as a result the coin’s weight was lessened from
3.1 to 2.5 grams, and the copper content was reduced from 95 to
2.5%. The five-cent coin weighting 5g (75% copper, 25% nickel) costs
Americans 4.5 cents, or 5.75 cents including production costs, which
exceeds the face value by 15%. The value of metal content in Russian coins may also be higher
than their face value… But the information on metal content in Russian
coins is restricted… In Russia, too, the cost of metal content is close to the face value. In a one-kopeck coin metal content exceeds
its face value by over 100% percent… In the early 1990-ies the Central
Bank of Russia even had to cease minting small change, as the then
First Deputy to the Central Bank President Arnold Voilukov confessed
in 2003: «Our coins contain copper and nickel, and thus reminting
them even with the help of rather primitive technologies would be
profitable" Even paper money may turn out to be cheaper than the material it is made of. The catastrophic inflation that hit Germany in 1922 (prices were multiplied by 5570) and 1923 (by 1300 billion) made banknotes more expensive than paper. And in 2003, a Web portal for travelers Inyourpocket.com, calculated that in Byelorussian restrooms it is cheaper to use one-rouble bills than toilet paper. However, in 2004 President Lukashenko withdrew one-rouble banknotes from circulation"146.» |
Copying information from this website is only allowed under condition of referring to this web link.
Copyright © 2008 Andrey Gribov
All rights reserved